Stratfor
January 15, 2014
By Robert D. Kaplan
Many years ago, I visited Four Corners in the American
Southwest. This is a small stone monument on a polished metal platform where
four states meet. You can walk around the monument in the space of a few
seconds and stand in four states: Arizona, New Mexico, Colorado and Utah.
People lined up to do this and have their pictures taken by excited relatives.
To walk around the monument is indeed a thrill, because each of these four
states has a richly developed tradition and identity that gives these borders
real meaning. And yet no passports or customs police are required to go from
one state to the other.
Well, of course that's true, they're only states, not
countries, you might say. But the fact that my observation is a dull
commonplace doesn't make it any less amazing. To be sure, it makes it more
amazing. For as the late Harvard Professor Samuel P. Huntington once remarked,
the genius of the American system lies less in its democracy per se than in its
institutions. The federal and state system featuring 50 separate identities and
bureaucracies, each with definitive land borders -- that nevertheless do not
conflict with each other -- is unique in political history. And this is not to
mention the thousands of counties and municipalities in America with their own
sovereign jurisdictions. Many of the countries I have covered as a reporter in
the troubled and war-torn developing world would be envious of such an original
institutional arrangement for governing an entire continent.
In fact, Huntington's observation can be expanded further:
The genius of Western civilization in general is that of institutions. Sure,
democracy is a basis for this; but democracy is, nevertheless, a separate
factor. For enlightened dictatorships in Asia have built robust, meritocratic
institutions whereas weak democracies in Africa have not.
Institutions are such a mundane element of Western
civilization that we tend to take them for granted. But as I've indicated, in
many places I have worked and lived, that is not the case. Getting a permit or
a simple document is not a matter of waiting in line for a few minutes, but of
paying bribes and employing fixers. We take our running water and dependable
electric current for granted, but those are amenities missing from many
countries and regions because of the lack of competent institutions to manage
such infrastructure. Having a friend or a relative working in the IRS is not
going to save you from paying taxes, but such a situation is a rarity
elsewhere. Successful institutions treat everyone equally and impersonally.
This is not the case in Russia or Pakistan or Nigeria.
Of course, Americans may complain about poor rail service
and deteriorating infrastructure and bureaucracies, especially in inner cities,
but it is important to realize that we are, nevertheless, complaining on the
basis of a very high standard relative to much of the developing world.
Institutions, or the lack of them, explain much that has
happened in the world in recent decades. Following the collapse of the Berlin
Wall, Central Europe went on to build functioning democracies and economies.
With all of their problems and challenges, the Baltic states, Poland, the Czech
Republic, Slovakia and Hungary have not fared badly and in some cases have been
rousing success stories. This is because these societies boast high literacy
rates among both men and women and have a tradition of modern bourgeois culture
prior to World War II and communism. And it is literacy and middle class
culture that are the building blocks of successful institutions. Institutions
after all require bureaucrats, who must, in turn, be literate and familiar with
the impersonal workings of modern organizations.
The Balkans have been less fortunate, with bad government
and unimpressive growth the fare in Romania since 1989, semi-chaos rearing its
head in Albania and Bulgaria, and inter-ethnic war destroying the Yugoslav
federation in the 1990s. Here, too, a history of lower literacy rates, weak or
in some cases non-existent middle classes, and an Eastern Orthodox faith that,
because it is more contemplative it does not encourage impersonal standards, at
least to the degree of Protestantism or even Catholicism, have all been factors
in a weaker institutional basis for economic growth and political stability.
Russia, too, fits into this category. Its system of oligarchs is a telltale
sign of weak institutions, since corruption merely indicates an alternative
pathway to getting things done when laws and the state bureaucracies are
inadequately developed.
Then there is the greater Middle East. The so-called Arab
Spring failed because the Arab world was not like Central and Eastern Europe.
It had low literacy, especially among women. It had little or no tradition of a
modern bourgeois, despite commercial classes in some cities, and so no usable
institutions to fall back upon once dictatorships crumbled. Thus, what was left
in North Africa and the Levant after authoritarianism was tribes and sects;
unlike the post-communist civil society that encouraged stability in Central
Europe. Turkey and Iran, as real states with more successful urbanization and higher
literacy rates, are in an intermediate category between southern Europe and the
Arab world. Obviously, even within the Arab world there are distinctions.
Egyptian state institutions are a reality to a degree that those in Syria and
Iraq are not. Egypt is governable, therefore, if momentarily by autocratic
means, whereas Syria and Iraq seem not to be.
Finally, there is Africa. In many African countries, when
taking a road out of the capital, very soon the state itself vanishes. The road
becomes a vague dirt track, and the domains of tribes and warlords take over.
This is a world where, because literacy and middle classes are minimal (albeit
growing), institutions still barely exist. The way to gauge development in
Africa is not to interview civil society types in the capitals, but to go to
the ministries and other bureaucracies and wait in line and see how things work
-- and if they do.
Indeed, people lie to themselves and then lie to journalists
and ambassadors. So don't listen to what people (especially elites) say; watch
how they behave. Do they pay taxes? Where do they stash their money? Do they
wait in line to get drivers' permits, and so forth? It is behavior, not
rhetoric, that indicates the existence of institutions, or lack thereof.
Elections are easy to hold and indicate less than
journalists and political scientists think. An election is a 24- or 48-hour
affair, organized often with the help of foreign observers. But a well-oiled
ministry must function 365 days a year. Lee Kuan Yew is one of the great men of
the 20th century because he built institutions and, therefore, a state in
Singapore. For without basic order there can be no meaningful freedom. And
institutions are the foremost tools of order.
Because institutions develop slowly and organically, even
under the best of circumstances, their growth eludes journalists who are
interested in dramatic events. Thus, media stories often provide a poor
indication of the prospects of a particular country. The lesson for
businesspeople and intelligence forecasters is: Track institutions, not
personalities.
No comments:
Post a Comment