December 31, 2013
By ADAM DAVIDSON
When my wife and I first visited the supersize Ikea in Red
Hook, Brooklyn, in 2008, we didn’t take time to stop for the lingonberry jam or
meatballs. Soon after we walked in, we just wanted to leave. We realized that
the place was a crowded, labyrinthine mess lacking the adequate amount of staff
to help us chose between the Ekby Hensvik and the Ekby Bjarnum. We left angry
and exhausted, and we swore — for the sake of our marriage — never to return.
Ikea, I thought, was just like Walmart or countless other big-box retailers
that seemed to have embraced a Faustian bargain with their customers. The
chains would sell absurdly inexpensive stuff — like a Lovbacken coffee table
for $60 — but as a consequence, customers would have to put up with huge stores
manned by small, often unhappy and unhelpful staffs.
One recent Sunday, however, my wife and I caved. We needed
to buy four separate closets and all the interior trimmings, and Ikea was the
only place we could find them for less than $600. Coincidentally, it was the
same weekend in which I was reading “The Good Jobs Strategy,” by Zeynep Ton, a
business professor at M.I.T.’s Sloan School of Management. Ton, 39, grew up in
Turkey and spent several summers working at her father’s apparel factory, often
sewing pockets for bathrobes. The job was, like many menial low-wage tasks,
both pressure-filled and boring, and Ton wished she could find a way to make
such workers happier. After a volleyball scholarship brought her to the United
States as a young adult, she eventually dedicated her academic career to
figuring out how to make low-paid work more rewarding for employees and employers
alike.
In the last few years, Ton has become a revolutionary force
in a field that would seem unlikely to generate many — the Kafkaesque-titled
Operations Management. Her central thesis is that many of those big-box
retailers have been making a strategic error: Even the most coldhearted,
money-hungry capitalists ought to realize that increasing their work force, and
paying them and treating them better, will often yield happier customers, more
engaged workers and — surprisingly — larger corporate profits. This sounds
Pollyannaish, sure, but a study co-authored by Marshall Fisher, a Wharton
professor who specializes in retail-management studies, backs it up. For every
dollar of increased wages, one retailer that was studied by Fisher brought in
$10 more in revenue. For more-understaffed stores in the study, the boost was
as high as $28.
The problem results from the way many companies consider
their workers. Ikea, for instance, has more than 130,000 global workers. In
order to manage all these people, it uses something called
work-force-management software, which ensures that there are enough workers —
but not too many — to handle the forecasted in-store shopping traffic.
(Walmart, which has 16 times as many workers, does, too, as do most larger
retailers.) The software typically codes workers as a cost — one of the biggest
— and aims to find the mostefficient number of employees that can
handle expected traffic. A trip to a big-box store reveals this algorithm’s
logic in practice. There always seem to be endless aisles of merchandise but no
one to answer your questions.
Ton, however, argues that workers are not merely a cost;
they can be a source of profit — a major one. A better-paid, better-trained
worker, she argues, will be more eager to help customers; they’ll also be more
eager to help their store sell to them. The success of Costco, Trader Joe’s,
QuikTrip and Mercadona, Spain’s biggest supermarket chain, indicate, she
argues, that well-paid, knowledgeable workers are not an indulgence often found
in luxury boutiques with their high markups. At each of the aforementioned
companies, workers are paid more than at their competitors; they are also amply
staffed per shift. More employees can ask customers questions about what they
want to see more of and what they don’t like, and then they are empowered to
change displays or order different stock to appeal to local tastes. (In big
chains, these sorts of decisions are typically made in headquarters with little
or no line-staff input.) Costco pays its workers about $21 an hour; Walmart is
just about $13. Yet Costco’s stock performance has thoroughly walloped
Walmart’s for a decade.
I was thinking about this as my wife and I re-entered Ikea.
From the moment we walked into the store, we realized that something changed. A
greeter at the entrance pointed out a shortcut to get to the closet department,
which probably saved us half an hour. When we got there, a salesman guided us
through the options. Suspicious that this was a fluke, I made a point of asking
questions of every worker we passed, but everyone was pleasant, knowledgeable
and helpful. Even on a crowded Sunday, there seemed to be plenty of roving
employees looking to answer, direct and expound upon the various differences
between the Pax and the Stuva closet systems — of which, I can now tell you,
there are many.
This wasn’t a fluke. A couple of days later, Rob Olson, the
C.F.O. of Ikea U.S., told me that since my last visit, the company had invested
in a new work-force-management system that reminded me of much of Ton’s thesis.
The software helps the company to better distribute workers throughout the
store, so that there are more of them in the areas where people have the most
questions, like closets. The new system was designed by Kronos, a large work-force-management
company (both The New York Times and my other employer, NPR, are customers).
Charles DeWitt, Kronos’s head of business development, told me that he and his
colleagues have been profoundly affected by Ton’s work and are building a new
set of work-force-management products designed to help retail chains enact some
of her ideas. Ikea’s system is only the beginning, he said. He has been
traveling the country selling the concept to other retailers.
Ton may have started her research in retail, but she
believes her core findings are relevant in nearly every industry. After
re-evaluating the relationship between worker management and profit, she argues
that many corporate leaders will realize that paying their workers more and
treating them better will actually make everyone better off. And this, indeed,
would foment a small revolution. For generations, technology has been a source
of misery for many low-paid workers, rendering their jobs tedious or
eliminating them altogether. Gallup recently reported that only 29 percent of
North American workers feel engaged with their work. Yet Ton suggests that a
more sophisticated use of those same technological tools could reverse those
trends. It’s possible that the lousy commodity jobs that we think of as central
to an industrialized economy — from Charlie Chaplin’s “Modern Times” to “Office
Space” to the latest disaster in Bangladesh — may not be a sad but inevitable
result of a bigger, more efficient economy; it may just be a math error. Ikea’s
decision to improve conditions for its workers is a major step forward.
Persuading Walmart, with its 1.3 million U.S. employees . . . well, that might
be a revolution.
Adam Davidson is co-founder of NPR’s “Planet Money,” a
podcast and blog.
No comments:
Post a Comment